Tariffs and taxes increase the cost of your product to the foreign buyer and may affect your competitiveness in the market. So knowing the final cost to your buyer can help you price your product for that market.
In addition, your buyer may ask you to quote an estimate of these costs before making the purchase. This estimate can be made via email, phone, or in the pro forma invoice. Some countries have very high duties and taxes, and others relatively low duties and taxes. If your product is primarily made in the U. The U. Below are steps for finding and calculating estimated tariffs and taxes. Only the customs officers in the country where the goods clear can make the final determination.
Schedules of market access commitments on goods by WTO Members There is no legally binding agreement that sets out the targets for tariff reductions. Instead, individual members of the WTO have listed their commitments to cut and bind tariffs on goods schedules that are part of the Uruguay Round Agreements. Additional commitments were made under the Information Technology Agreement.
In simplest terms, a tariff is a tax. It adds to the cost borne by consumers of imported goods and is one of several trade policies that a country can enact. Tariffs are paid to the customs authority of the country imposing the tariff. Tariffs on imports coming into the United States, for example, are collected by Customs and Border Protection, acting on behalf of the Commerce Department. It is important to recognize that the taxes owed on imports are paid by domestic consumers and not imposed directly on the foreign country's exports.
Often, goods from abroad are cheaper because they offer cheaper capital or labor costs; if those goods become more expensive, then consumers will choose the relatively costlier domestic product. Overall, consumers tend to lose out with tariffs, where the taxes are collected domestically.
Tariffs are often created to protect infant industries and developing economies but are also used by more advanced economies with developed industries. The levying of tariffs is often highly politicized. The possibility of increased competition from imported goods can threaten domestic industries.
These domestic companies may fire workers or shift production abroad to cut costs, which means higher unemployment and a less happy electorate.
The unemployment argument often shifts to domestic industries complaining about cheap foreign labor, and how poor working conditions and lack of regulation allow foreign companies to produce goods more cheaply. In economics, however, countries will continue to produce goods until they no longer have a comparative advantage not to be confused with an absolute advantage. A government may levy a tariff on products that it feels could endanger its population. For example, South Korea may place a tariff on imported beef from the United States if it thinks that the goods could be tainted with a disease.
The use of tariffs to protect infant industries can be seen by the Import Substitution Industrialization ISI strategy employed by many developing nations.
The government of a developing economy will levy tariffs on imported goods in industries in which it wants to foster growth. This increases the prices of imported goods and creates a domestic market for domestically produced goods while protecting those industries from being forced out by more competitive pricing. It decreases unemployment and allows developing countries to shift from agricultural products to finished goods. Criticisms of this sort of protectionist strategy revolve around the cost of subsidizing the development of infant industries.
If an industry develops without competition, it could wind up producing lower quality goods, and the subsidies required to keep the state-backed industry afloat could sap economic growth. Barriers are also employed by developed countries to protect certain industries that are deemed strategically important, such as those supporting national security. Defense industries are often viewed as vital to state interests, and often enjoy significant levels of protection.
For example, while both Western Europe and the United States are industrialized, both are very protective of defense-oriented companies. Countries may also set tariffs as a retaliation technique if they think that a trading partner has not played by the rules. For example, if France believes that the United States has allowed its wine producers to call its domestically produced sparkling wines "Champagne" a name specific to the Champagne region of France for too long, it may levy a tariff on imported meat from the United States.
If the U. Retaliation can also be employed if a trading partner goes against the government's foreign policy objectives. There are several types of tariffs and barriers that a government can employ:. A fixed fee levied on one unit of an imported good is referred to as a specific tariff. This tariff can vary according to the type of goods imported. The phrase "ad valorem" is Latin for "according to value," and this type of tariff is levied on a good based on a percentage of that good's value.
This price increase protects domestic producers from being undercut but also keeps prices artificially high for Japanese car shoppers. A license is granted to a business by the government and allows the business to import a certain type of good into the country.
For example, there could be a restriction on imported cheese, and licenses would be granted to certain companies allowing them to act as importers. The bound tariff is the maximum MFN tariff level for a given commodity line. When countries join the WTO or when WTO members negotiate tariff levels with each other during trade rounds, they make agreements about bound tariff rates, rather than actually applied rates.
Members have the flexibility increase or decrease their tariffs on a non-discriminatory basis so long as they didn't raise them above their bound levels. If one WTO member raises applied tariffs above their bound level, other WTO members can take the country to dispute settlement. If the country did not reduced applied tariffs below their bound levels, other countries could request compensation in the form of higher tariffs of their own.
In other words, the applied tariff is less than or equal to the bound tariff in practice for any particular product. The gap between the bound and applied MFN rates is called the binding overhang. Trade economists argue that a large binding overhang makes a country's trade policies less predictable. This gap tends to be small on average in industrial countries and often fairly large in developing countries as illustrated below.
The binding coverage the share of tariff lines with WTO-bound rates also varies across countries. Until the Uruguay Round of the GATT, which ended in , countries agreed to bind tariffs only on manufactured goods; trade in agricultural products was excluded from the GATT when it was written in the lates.
0コメント